Bernanke Talks, Markets
Wobble. There Must Be a Better Way
Rep. Kevin Brady's Centennial Monetary
Commission initiative might point toward a useful policy overhaul.
Since Federal Reserve
Chairman Ben Bernanke testified before Congress's Joint Economic Committee
Wednesday morning, commenting on the economic outlook and responding to
questions from lawmakers on the likely path of monetary policy, financial
markets have experienced turmoil. Triple-digit gains in the Dow Jones
Industrial Average turned negative later that afternoon. That spurred a 7.3%
plunge in the Japanese stock market, which in turn dragged down bourses in
Frankfurt, London, Paris and Rome on Thursday morning—sending U.S. stocks on a
roller-coaster ride.
Mr. Bernanke must be
thinking: "Was it something I said?"
We should be asking
ourselves a different question: Does it make sense for financial and economic
outcomes to be so highly dependent on the pronouncements of a single
individual? Would it be better if monetary policy were more rules-based and
less discretionary?
In the midst of
heightened concern over the hazards of overreaching government agencies, this
may be a propitious moment to review the Fed's outsize role in determining the
price and availability of capital. Instead of granting sweeping powers based on
the judgment of its chairman—or relying on the collective omniscience of its
12-member Federal Open Market Committee—we would do well to examine whether
some objective rule or standard might better calibrate the supply of money and
credit to the needs of the real economy.
Fortuitously, the Joint
Economic Committee's chairman, Rep. Kevin Brady (R., Texas), introduced
legislation two months ago to begin that examination. The Centennial Monetary
Commission Act of 2013 would establish a commission to analyze whether the Fed
has improved economic performance or whether an alternative monetary regime
based on a specific target—in terms of an inflation index, nominal gross
domestic product, or the price of gold—might provide a more stable platform for
productive growth. As Rep. Brady bluntly told Mr. Bernanke at Wednesday's
hearing, "My worry is that the Fed doesn't have the prescription for what
ails our economy."
Clearly, the Fed hasn't
shied away from prescriptions. In his legislation, Mr. Brady cites the
extraordinary actions taken in recent years with regard to "multiple
rounds of quantitative easing, providing unprecedented liquidity to financial
markets, while committing to holding short-term interest rates low for a
seemingly indefinite period, and pursuing a policy of credit allocation by purchasing
Federal agency debt and mortgage-backed securities."
These moves by our
central bank might be construed as going beyond any reasonable definition of
limited government. Yet it is important to note that the Brady initiative does
not seek to push an ideological agenda but rather to gather facts. The monetary
commission would be charged with scrutinizing economic data on output,
employment, prices and financial stability associated with various monetary
systems during our nation's history, particularly since the creation of the
Federal Reserve System in 1913.
The Constitution grants
authority to "coin money" and regulate its value to Congress—not the
Federal Reserve—so it is entirely appropriate at the 100-year mark to authorize
a congressional review of the government agency to which monetary powers have
been delegated. Indeed, given the Fed's dominant role in financing the national
debt, it is important to evaluate its decisions in terms of fiscal complicity.
What, for instance, is the impact of prolonged monetary accommodation on the
growth of government? And how does it impact private-sector initiative?
It also makes sense to
evaluate the potential benefits of moving toward a different operational
approach or alternative monetary regime. Should we continue to rely on the
discretion of monetary officials to get it right? Or would inherent free-market
mechanisms better allocate financial capital if the private sector knew in
advance that monetary policy was based on an observable, well-defined target
and adjustments were automatically implemented?
There is no guarantee
that a Centennial Monetary Commission would end up recommending anything beyond
the status quo, of course. Plenty of people consider Mr. Bernanke's flexibility
to push up stocks, bonds, housing prices and other assets through unorthodox
methods as essential for recovery. Even if there is uneasiness about the ad hoc
quality of such actions—with the FOMC sometimes making up monetary policy as it
goes along—investment portfolios have mostly recouped losses suffered in the
wake of the 2008 financial crisis.
Then again, there are
many others who point to the Fed's inability to predict and its culpability in
fueling that crisis. So even if pumped-up asset prices provide some comfort, it
doesn't mean that our current discretionary monetary regime is the best way to
deliver long-term economic growth. Short memories do not serve the cause of
sound money.
How best, then, can
Congress carry out its monetary responsibility to provide money in keeping with
constitutional precepts? It is clear that the Founders meant for Congress to
ensure that the nation's monetary standard would be as reliable and
well-defined as its other official measures. Lawmakers should remember that the
power to regulate the value of money is enumerated in the same sentence
(Article I, Section 8) as the power to fix the standard of weights and
measures.
That is precisely why we
need a bipartisan commission to evaluate the Fed's monetary decision-making
process in both quantitative and qualitative terms. Is monetary policy
determined in a way consistent with American principles—or have we turned away
from the rule of law for the rule of men.
Ms. Shelton is a senior fellow at the Atlas
Economic Research Foundation and co-director of the Sound Money Project.
This article is from the Wall Street Journal.
No comments:
Post a Comment