Price
controls
From Wikipedia, the free
encyclopedia
Price controls are governmental restrictions on the prices that can be
charged for goods and services in a market. The intent behind implementing
such controls can stem from the desire to maintain affordability of staple foods
and goods, to prevent price gouging
during shortages, and to slow inflation, or, alternatively, to insure a minimum
income for providers of certain goods or a minimum wage.
There are two primary forms of price control, a price ceiling,
the maximum price that can be charged, and a price floor,
the minimum price that can be charged.
Historically, price controls have
often been imposed as part of a larger incomes policy
package also employing wage controls and other regulatory elements.
Although price controls are often
used by governments, economists usually agree that price controls don't
accomplish what they are intended to do and are generally to be avoided.[1]
Historical
examples
An early example of this type of
policy is attested to in the Old Testament,
where the Israelites were instructed not to charge interest
on other Israelites.[1]
The Roman Emperor Diocletian
tried to set maximum prices for all commodities in the end of the 3rd century CE, but
with little success.
Price controls have also been used
in modern times for such things as rent control
and usury
laws.[1]
During World War I, the United States Food Administration
enforced price controls on food.[2][3][4][5]
Price controls were also imposed in the US and Nazi Germany during WWII.[6][7]
States have sometimes chosen to
implement their own control policies. California
controls the prices of electricity within the state, which economist Thomas Sowell
blames for the occasional electricity shortages the state experiences.[8]
Sowell said of California's controls in 2001: "Since the utility companies
have been paying more for electricity than they were allowed to charge their
customers, they were operating in the red and the financial markets are
downgrading their bonds."[8]
California's price-setting board has agreed to raise rates, but not as much as
the companies were paying on the wholesale market for their electricity.[9]
Economist Lawrence Makovich contended, "We've already seen in California
that price caps on retail rates increased demand and made the shortage worse
and price caps also forced the largest utility, Pacific Gas and Electric, into
bankruptcy in four months."[10]
While some charged that electricity providers had in past years charged
above-market rates,[10]
in 2002 the San
Francisco Chronicle reported
that before the blackouts, many energy providers left the state because they
could make a greater profit in other Western states.[11]
The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission stepped in and set price caps
for each megawatt
of power bought, after lifting the caps to avoid rolling blackouts six months previously.[11]
The state of Hawaii briefly introduced a cap on the
wholesale price of gasoline in an effort to fight "price gouging"
in that state in 2005. Because it was widely seen as too soft and ineffective,
it was repealed shortly thereafter.[citation needed]
Criticisms
The primary criticism leveled
against price controls is that by keeping prices artificially low, demand is
increased to the point where supply can not keep up, leading to shortages in
the price-controlled product.[12]
For example, Lactantius wrote that Diocletian
"by various taxes he had made all things exceedingly expensive, attempted
by a law to limit their prices. Then much blood [of merchants] was shed for
trifles, men were afraid to offer anything for sale, and the scarcity became
more excessive and grievous than ever. Until, in the end, the [price limit]
law, after having proved destructive to many people, was from mere necessity abolished."[13]
As with Diocletian's Edict on Maximum Prices, shortages lead to black markets
where prices for the same good exceed those of an uncontrolled market.[12]
Furthermore, once controls are removed, prices will immediately increase, which
can temporarily shock the economic system.[12]
A classic example of how price
controls cause shortages was during the Arab oil embargo between October 19, 1973 and March 17, 1974. Long lines of cars and trucks quickly appeared at retail
gas stations in the U.S. and some stations closed because of a shortage of fuel
at the low price set by the U.S. Cost of Living Council. The fixed price was
below what the market would otherwise bear and, as a result, the inventory
disappeared. It made no difference whether prices were voluntarily or
involuntarily posted below the market clearing price. Scarcity resulted in
either case. Price controls fail to achieve their proximate aim, which is to
reduce prices paid by retail consumers, but such controls do manage to reduce
supply.[14][15]
When price controls on gasoline were lifted, the shortage ended and the long
lines of cars at gas pumps disappeared.
Nobel
prize winner Milton Friedman
said "We economists don't know much, but we do know how to create a
shortage. If you want to create a shortage of tomatoes, for example, just pass
a law that retailers can't sell tomatoes for more than two cents per pound.
Instantly you'll have a tomato shortage. It's the same with oil or gas."[16]
Nixon's
Secretary
of the Treasury, George Shultz,
enacting Nixon's "New Economic Policy," lifted price controls that
had begun in 1971. This lifting of price controls resulted in a rapid increase
in prices. Price freezes were re-established five months later.[17]
The entire wiki link can be found at:
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Price_controls
No comments:
Post a Comment